The Australian Government’s agenda for the reform of the health system is now under consideration.1,2 The National Primary Health Care Strategy recommends “pay-for-performance” as a key building block:
Progressive introduction of pay-for-performance arrangements which are linked to improvement of patient health outcomes to support participation in the framework and continual quality improvement activities.
... there is scope for these types of incentives to play a much larger role in achieving improved health outcomes.1
It has already been announced that the federal government is to take responsibility for all primary care funding and policy. Patients with diabetes will be encouraged to voluntarily enrol with a general practice for care of a chronic condition; capitation payments (set amounts paid to doctors for enrolled patients) will be made, and pay will be linked to performance. Given Australia’s past experience with pay-for-performance through the Practice Incentives Program (PIP), many of the conditions for the extension of a pay-for-performance scheme in Australian primary care seem to be in place. However, pay-for-performance can be expensive,3 and rigorous evidence that it leads to improvements in quality of care is lacking.
The aim of our article is to consider the international experience of pay-for-performance in primary care, identify the key lessons learned, and use these to examine what questions Australia may need to consider before such a scheme is introduced.
The Quality and Outcomes Framework (QOF) is a national primary care pay-for-performance scheme in the United Kingdom,4 described as “world-leading” at its introduction in 2004. The UK Government invested up to 20% of the primary care budget on the scheme, 90% of which was money additional to the existing health budget. Since 2004, there has been an increasing focus on clinical indicators (eg, the percentage of people with heart disease or with blood pressure below a defined target) (Box 1), which represented 52% of the framework in 2004, and increased to 66% in 2006 and 70% in 2009. Although the QOF is a voluntary system, over 99% of UK practices participate in it.5 Points are awarded for individual indicators in relation to the level of achievement of that indicator. There is a graduated scale of payments, from a minimum (25% initially, rising to 40% in 2006) to a maximum (usually 90%) once maximum points are reached.
The United States has the most diversity in pay-for-performance schemes in health care.6,7 There are hundreds of such schemes within US health maintenance organisations (HMOs), and some of these are large schemes involving coordination across a number of private health insurers.8 US national schemes are currently being developed and evaluated within the US Medicare system.9
There are few well designed empirical evaluations of the impact of pay-for-performance schemes.10,11 We reviewed the evidence from the UK, US and Australia and identified several important factors that should be considered when designing such schemes.12
It is crucial to account for intrinsic and contextual factors which may accompany the introduction of pay-for-performance. Schemes evolve over time and usually involve several complex interventions, including accreditation, education, quality improvement programs (eg, guidelines and feedback), investment in information technology (IT) and data collection systems, and professional and regional support structures.12 These are all necessary conditions for linking financial incentives to quality of care. In the UK, there was a long history of structural reform, performance management, clinical guideline development and development of IT infrastructure before the QOF was introduced. Critically, it was possible to collect good quality data on current baselines for quality of care from some general practices.13 Performance pay in the UK relies on data collection at the practice level. The QOF uses electronic data entry and extraction processes using agreed clinical terms (Read codes). There are no comparable nationally computerised clinical information systems in Australia, although some progress has been made through the Australian Primary Care Collaboratives. In the US, and in the Australian PIP, administrative data based on fee claims are used to calculate performance measures. This approach does not lend itself to a pay-for-performance scheme that covers multiple disease areas, because fee claims are indicators of process of care, not clinical outcomes.
The first rule of the QOF in the UK is “first, create a register”. This is possible because patients enrol with only one general practice. These registers focus predominantly on single conditions (eg, diabetes), but as the population ages and multiple morbidity is increasingly the norm, there is a need for measures that take into account the number and severity of conditions at an individual level. In Australia, disease registers are kept by practices in the PIP and by accredited practices, so enrolment is not strictly necessary for the maintenance of registers. However, enrolment would strengthen a pay-for-performance system, as it makes it easier to attribute changes in quality and performance to a specific provider responsible for coordinating the health care of patients.7 The incentives may be weaker if a patient visits multiple providers, since providers may be less likely to feel “responsible” or feel they have less control over patient outcomes. Enrolment for all patients could also prevent undesirable “double dipping” (patients appearing on the disease registers of more than one practice).
In the UK, negotiations to implement the QOF were simplified because a single funder (the UK Department of Health) could negotiate with doctors’ representatives and agree on a new national general practitioner contract. With multiple funders, the effects of incentives introduced by any one funder will be less effective. Experience from the US suggests that when a doctor contracts with multiple insurers or HMOs, a single HMO has less influence on changing GP behaviour. The scheme coordinated by the Integrated Healthcare Association in California has greater influence because it is a collaboration of several insurers in California that use pay-for-performance schemes covering 17% of the population (6.2 million people). The insurers pay 60% of the capitation payments to medical groups.7,14 In Australia, the federal government currently funds most GP services, but non-GP primary care services are often funded by state governments. Planned reform includes the federal government becoming the sole government funder of primary care services. Patients will continue to contribute through copayments, which could dilute the effect of a pay-for-performance scheme.
The UK QOF policy documents do not mention rewarding improvement in quality of care, just “providing” it. None of the incentives reward quality improvements, only achieving targets for “intermediate” outcome measures.15 No scheme directly measures or rewards improvements in health, as patients’ health-related quality of life before and after interventions is not routinely measured. The Californian Integrated Healthcare Association scheme had clear objectives for rewarding improvements in quality, but the incentives actually rewarded attainment of target levels of performance or position in relative rankings, not change or improvement. The US Medicare Physician Group Practice Demonstration scheme includes both threshold targets to reward achievement and an improvement target.9
There are several reasons why rewarding the achievement of a specified level of quality may not be as effective as rewarding improvements in quality. First, for those already providing high-quality care, the reward represents a windfall financial gain with no incentive to change behaviour. The QOF could be regarded as another way of paying GPs, rather than encouraging improvements in quality of care through changed behaviour. Second, rewarding the achievement of a threshold of quality does not encourage further improvements in quality beyond the threshold. Third, for doctors with very low baseline levels of quality, the costs of achieving a relatively high threshold may seem prohibitive and they may not participate. These are the very groups where substantial gains in quality of care could be made at little additional cost.
Rewarding improvements in quality would encourage those with low baseline levels of quality to improve their care (ie, where the largest increases are likely to be made).6,16,17 This can be achieved either by setting successive thresholds close together (eg, at 5% intervals) or to pay only when a certain increase has been achieved (eg, a 5% increase). Additional costs for those achieving a given change in quality from a low baseline are likely to be lower than the costs for those already providing high-quality care, where the “easy” gains have already been made. The increasing costs of achieving each successive improvement should then be reflected in the payment schedule. Rewards for those who already provide high-quality care, but find it difficult to improve any further, should be part of a background payment scheme rather than a key element of the pay-for-performance scheme.
Possible unintended consequences, such as a focus on the remunerated areas at the cost of unremunerated areas (“gaming”), need to be thought through and managed carefully. Few empirical studies have examined potential adverse consequences of pay-for-performance.18 The QOF was intended to reward quality of care rather than numbers of registered patients, and also to improve data capture, care processes, patient outcomes and doctors’ working conditions.4 However, evidence suggests that over the lifetime of the QOF, patients in the UK now find it harder to obtain continuity of care.19 Other evidence from the UK suggests that there were positive spillovers to unremunerated disease areas.20,21 A practice that provides high-quality care in one disease area is also likely to provide high-quality care in other disease areas.
Gravelle and colleagues found that UK GPs who failed to score maximum QOF points in the first year “gamed” the system by increasing their exception-reported patients (patients who would not count in their QOF scores) in the following years.22 “Patient dumping” is therefore another risk in pay-for-performance schemes.18 There is also a risk that external incentives may crowd out intrinsic motivation (the desire to do a task well for its own sake), especially if the external incentives are not closely aligned to doctors’ views of their role.23 Current evidence suggests that financial incentives are most likely to be effective in influencing professional behaviour when performance measures and rewards are aligned to the values of the staff being rewarded.24
In the UK, practice nurses have absorbed a higher proportion of the clinical workload associated with the QOF.23 One unintended consequence is that nurses do not benefit directly from the incentives that drive their work.25 Payments to individual professionals may not encourage team work or coordination of care (and thus may not improve quality of care when team-based coordinated care is needed) if there are large differences in payments between team members.25
A balance needs to be achieved in deciding how much funding will be allocated to pay-for-performance schemes. The QOF substantially overspent initially, because GP performance was underestimated before the scheme was introduced.26 Additional government spending on health care was used to fund the scheme, including a substantial increase in doctors’ incomes of 35% over 2 years, when the scheme was introduced. The 20%–25% of doctor income that comes from the QOF contrasts sharply with the experience of using pay-for-performance in the US, where rewards were less than 10% of revenue, which may not have been large enough to cover the costs of changing behaviour.6-8 Incentives were funded from within existing budgets or savings, and so for some schemes no new resources were invested. Australian Medicare data from 2003 suggest that the PIP represented an average of 9% of GPs’ revenue from Medicare,27 though only a proportion of this would have been used for the pay-for-performance elements (service incentive payments [SIPs]28 and outcome payments). There is little evidence to suggest what proportion of revenue should be paid using pay-for-performance, but the 20%–25% of revenue in the QOF is likely to be too high.
There should be a mix of payments to the practice and to individual health professionals for quality improvements. There is little evidence to suggest that one or the other should be targeted.29 Paying teams raises issues of how a team is defined, and how the financial rewards are used by the team.3,30 These issues may mitigate the intended effect of the financial incentives, though it does give discretion to the team to use the rewards in a number of ways, which might include investing in further quality improvements, or directly rewarding team members, or a combination.17 Any payments to team members should be equitable with respect to their skill and effort, or those who feel unfairly treated may lose motivation to change behaviour.
Pay-for-performance in Australia should evolve. It is not possible to transplant a system such as the QOF to Australia, mainly because Australia does not currently have the IT infrastructure to support such a scheme. However, Australia already has a pay-for-performance scheme, with SIPs and outcome (threshold) payments for diabetes, cervical screening and Indigenous health. A practice-level data collection and reporting system is also being developed and used in the Australian Primary Care Collaboratives. These schemes could be built on and developed, while taking into account the key lessons learnt from overseas.
The PIP is already evolving. The new Indigenous health incentive requires voluntary patient enrolment as well as performance incentives. The recent announcement of voluntary enrolment for diabetes patients, along with capitation payments to practices and performance payments (yet to be defined), is an important step in this direction. Even without this, there is a strong argument for changing the existing SIP program, and re-investing the resources into revised outcome payments providing rewards for annual percentage improvements in patients receiving completed cycles of care. In the longer term, investment in quality improvement and reporting requires investment in an integrated IT infrastructure.
If pay-for-performance is to be introduced into Australia, key lessons should be learned from the experiences of other countries (Box 2). In particular, pay-for-performance should be used only as one part of a wider, multiple-systems-based strategy for quality improvement, and should not be seen as a panacea. Pay-for-performance should be used explicitly to drive quality improvement, and not simply to reward those who are already providing high-quality care. Before such a scheme is contemplated, the method of data entry and extraction should be considered a key priority, with IT specialists included early in discussions.
2 Key implemention factors for pay-for-performance in Australia
Pay-for-performance should be one part of a wider strategy for quality improvement.
Data collection systems need to be developed. The mix of organisational, clinical and patient experience indicators need to be articulated and agreed on.
The purpose of pay-for-performance should be rewarding quality improvement, with quality maintenance rewarded using existing payment systems.
Stable, enrolled populations and a single funder will strengthen incentives.
There is little evidence on the optimal proportion of revenue from pay-for-performance. The United Kingdom proportion of 20%–25% is likely to be too high; in the United States it is usually less than 10%.
Incentives for teams or individuals should be carefully considered.
Unintended consequences should be carefully considered.
- Stephen M Campbell1
- Anthony Scott2
- Rhian M Parker3
- Lucio Naccarella2
- John S Furler2
- Doris Young2
- Peter M Sivey2
- 1 National Primary Care Research and Development Centre, University of Manchester, Manchester, UK.
- 2 University of Melbourne, Melbourne, VIC.
- 3 Australian Primary Health Care Research Institute, Australian National University, Canberra, ACT.
Some of this research is a project of the Australian Primary Health Care Research Institute, which is supported by a grant from the Australian Government Department of Health and Ageing under the Primary Health Care Research, Evaluation and Development Strategy. The information and opinions are ours and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Australian Government Department of Health and Ageing.
John Furler has been supported by an Australian Primary Health Care Research Institute (APHCRI) Stream 13 grant and he has received several other grants from the APHCRI. Anthony Scott has been funded by an APHCRI Stream 13 grant. Peter Sivey has been supported by the APHCRI, which is supported by the Australian Government Department of Health and Ageing. Doris Young has been funded by an APHCRI Stream 13 grant.
- 1. Australian Government Department of Health and Ageing. Primary health care reform in Australia. Report to support Australia’s first national primary health care strategy. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia, 2009. http://www.yourhealth.gov.au/internet/yourhealth/publishing.nsf/Content/nphc-draftreportsupp-toc/$FILE/NPHC-supp.pdf (accessed Aug 2010).
- 2. Australian Government. A healthier future for all Australians — final report. Commonwealth of Australia: Canberra, 2009. http://www.health.gov.au/internet/nhhrc/publishing.nsf/Content/nhhrc-report (accessed Aug 2010).
- 3. Campbell SM, McDonald R, Lester H. The experience of pay for performance in English family practice: a qualitative study. Ann Fam Med 2008; 6: 228-234.
- 4. Roland M. Linking physicians’ pay to the quality of care — a major experiment in the United Kingdom. N Engl J Med 2004; 351: 1448-1454.
- 5. Campbell SM, Reeves D, Kontopantelis E, et al. Effects of pay for performance on the quality of primary care in England. N Engl J Med 2009; 361: 368-378.
- 6. Rosenthal MB, Frank RG, Li Z, Epstein AM. Early experience with pay-for-performance: from concept to practice. JAMA 2005; 294: 1788-1793.
- 7. Rosenthal MB, Landon BE, Normand SL, et al. Pay for performance in commercial HMOs. N Engl J Med 2006; 355: 1895-1902.
- 8. Mullen K, Frank RG, Rosenthal MB. Can you get what you pay for? Pay-for-performance and the quality of healthcare providers. Rand J Econ 2010. In press.
- 9. Leavitt MO. Report to Congress: Physician Group Practice Demonstration first evaluation report. Washington, DC: United States Department of Health and Human Services, 2006.
- 10. Christianson JB, Leatherman S, Sutherland K. Financial incentives, healthcare providers and quality improvements: a review of the evidence. London: Quest for Quality and Improved Performance, The Health Foundation, 2007. http://www.health.org.uk/publications/research_reports/financial.html (accessed Aug 2010).
- 11. Scott A, Sivey P, Ait Ouakrim D, et al. The effect of financial incentives on the quality of health care provided by primary care physicians (protocol). Cochrane Database Syst Rev 2010; (4): CD008451.
- 12. Scott A, Nacarella L, Furler J, et al. Using financial incentives to improve the quality of primary care in Australia. Final report. Canberra: Australian Primary Health Care Research Institute, Australian National University, 2010.
- 13. Campbell SM, Steiner A, Robison J, et al. Is the quality of care in general medical practice improving? Results of a longitudinal observational study. Br J Gen Pract 2003; 53: 298-304.
- 14. Rosenthal MB, Landon BE, Howitt K, et al. Climbing up the pay-for-performance learning curve: where are the early adopters now? Health Aff 2007; 26: 1674-1682.
- 15. Department of Health (UK). Investing in general practice: the new general medical services contract. London: National Health Service Confederation and the British Medical Association, 2003. http://www.dh.gov.uk/en/Publicationsandstatistics/Publications/PublicationsPolicyAndGuidance/DH_4071966 (accessed Sep 2010).
- 16. Bokhour BG, Burgess JF Jr, Hook JM, et al. Incentive implementation in physician practices: a qualitative study of practice executive perspectives on pay for performance. Med Care Res Rev 2006; 63: 73S-95S.
- 17. Rosenthal MB, Fernandopulle R, Song HR, Landon B. Paying for quality: providers’ incentives for quality improvement. Health Aff 2004; 23: 127-141.
- 18. McDonald R, Roland M. Pay for performance in primary care in England and California: comparison of unintended consequences. Ann Fam Med 2009; 7: 121-127.
- 19. Campbell SM, Kontopantelis E, Reeves D, et al. Changes in patient experiences of primary care during health service reforms in England between 2003 and 2007. Ann Fam Med 2010. In press.
- 20. Sutton M, Elder R, Guthrie B, Watt G. Record rewards: the effects of targeted quality incentives on the recording of risk factors by primary care providers. Health Econ 2010; 19: 1-13.
- 21. Steel N, Maisey S, Clark A, et al. Quality of clinical primary care and targeted incentive payments: an observational study. Br J Gen Pract 2007; 57: 449-454.
- 22. Gravelle H, Sutton M, Ma A. Doctor behaviour under a pay for performance contract: further evidence from the quality and outcomes framework. York: Centre for Health Economics, University of York, 2008.
- 23. McDonald R, Campbell S, Lester HE. Practice nurses and the effects of the new general practitioner contract in the English National Health Service: the extension of a professional project? Soc Sci Med 2009; 68: 1206-1212.
- 24. Marshall M, Smith P. Rewarding results: using financial incentives to improve quality. Qual Saf Health Care 2003; 12: 397-398.
- 25. McDonald R, Harrison S, Checkland K, et al. Impact of financial incentives on clinical autonomy and internal motivation in primary care: ethnographic study. BMJ 2007; 334: 1333-1334.
- 26. National Audit Office (UK). NHS pay modernisation: new contracts for general practice services in England. London: Stationery Office, 2008.
- 27. Senate Select Committee on Medicare. Medicare: healthcare or welfare? Canberra: Senate Printing Unit, Parliament House, 2003.
- 28. Richardson J, Walsh J, Pegram R. Financing general practice, health services and expenditures. In: Pegram R, editor. General practice in Australia: 2004. Canberra: Department of Health and Ageing, 2005.
- 29. Naccarella L, Scott A, Furler J, et al. Narrative literature review on incentives for primary health care team service provision: learning and working together in primary health care. Canberra: Australian Primary Health Care Research Institute, Australian National University, 2010.
- 30. Forrest CB, Villagra VV, Pope JE. Managing the metric vs managing the patient: the physician’s view of pay for performance. Am J Manag Care 2006; 12: 83-85.
Abstract
We identify key lessons learned from the international experience of pay-for-performance and use them to formulate questions for Australia to consider before such a scheme is introduced.
Discussion of lessons learned is based on a narrative review of the literature.
We examined international evidence on factors to consider when designing pay-for-performance schemes, and the impact of these schemes on primary care practitioner behaviour and on primary care funding.
Pay-for-performance schemes evolve over time, and usually involve several complex interventions including accreditation, education, quality improvement programs, investment in information technology and data collection systems, professional support and regional structures. These are all necessary conditions for linking financial incentives to quality of care.
There is a strong argument for changing the existing service incentive payments program and investing the resources into revised outcome payments that provide rewards for annual improvements in numbers of patients receiving completed cycles of care.
If pay-for-performance is to be introduced in Australia, several key lessons should be learned from the experiences of other countries. Pay-for-performance should be used as part of a wider strategy for quality improvement; it should not be seen as a panacea. Pay-for-performance should be used to drive quality improvement, not simply to reward those who are already providing high-quality care.